DOI: 10.5553/EJLR/138723702021023002004

European Journal of Law ReformAccess_open

Article

Compensation for Victims of Disasters

A Comparative Law and Economic Perspective

Keywords victim compensation, disaster risk reduction, government relief, insurance, moral hazard, public private partnership
Authors
DOI
Show PDF Show fullscreen
Abstract Author's information Statistics Citation
This article has been viewed times.
This article been downloaded 0 times.
Suggested citation
Qihao He and Michael Faure, 'Compensation for Victims of Disasters', (2021) European Journal of Law Reform 222-241

    This article provides a critical analysis of the compensation awarded for victims of disasters. First, general guiding principles of compensation are discussed. Next, various ways of government provided victim compensation, both during the disaster and ex post are critically reviewed. Then the article focuses on ex ante insurance mechanisms for victim compensation, arguing that insurance can play a role in disaster risk reduction. Finally, the article explains how the government can cooperate with insurers in a public-private partnership for victim compensation, thus facilitating the availability of disaster insurance.

Dit artikel wordt geciteerd in

    • A Introduction

      The international community is facing many challenges under extreme conditions. Taking a look at the archives of the Minerva Center for the Rule of Law under Extreme Conditions, it shows the increasing frequency and severity of a broad range of disasters.1x Archive: Media Reports on Natural Disasters, available at: http://minervaextremelaw.haifa.ac.il/index.php/en/media-reports/24-media-reports/natural-disasters/237-archive-media-reports-on-natural-disasters-2017. For example, just in the past year (2018), over 800 people had been confirmed killed by a deadly 7.5-magnitude earthquake and tsunami in eastern Indonesia; and a large-scale flooding caused by Hurricane Florence hit Cape Verde and Bermuda, and the United States badly.2x Ibid. Such disaster stories are repeated and updated in the archives day after day. Given the prediction that disasters will become more frequent, more intense and more costly in the future,3x Muthukumara Mani, Michael Keen & Paul K. Freeman, Dealing with Increased Risk of Natural Disasters: Challenges and Options, IMF Working Paper, 2003, available at: www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2003/wp03197.pdf. there is an urgent need for the international community to engage in disaster risk management and to facilitate public and private mechanisms to compensate victims.
      Disaster management and compensation are central on the current public and political agendas. The 2001 9/11 terrorism attack and the 2005 Hurricane Katrina in the United States,4x Saul Levmore & Kyle D. Logue, Insuring Against Terrorism and Crime, 102, Mich. L. Rev., 268, 2003; Ronald J. Daniels, Donald F. Kettl & Howard Kunreuther, On Risk and Disaster: Lessons from Hurricane Katrina, 2006; William M. Taylor, Michael P. Levine, Oenone Rooksby & Joely-Kym Sobott, The ‘Katrina Effect’: On the Nature of Catastrophe, 2015. the 2002 Elbe flood in Europe5x Reinhard Mechler & Jürgen Weichselgartner, Disaster Loss Financing in Germany – The Case of the Elbe River Floods 2002, IIASA Interim Report, IR-03-021, 2003. and the 2008 Great Sichuan Earthquake in China6x Qihao He, Climate Change, Catastrophe Risk, and Government Stimulation of the Insurance Market: A Study of Transitional China, in J. Jay Choi, Michael R. Powers & Xiaotian Tina Zhang (Eds.), The Political Economy of Chinese Finance, 295-340, 2016. are typical events nurturing the active political discourse. To respond to the question whether and how it is feasible to compensate disaster victims and to control the costs of such disasters, the legal system could play an important role in governing a broad range of disasters in the rule of law societies.7x Daniel Farber & Michael Faure, Introduction, in Daniel Farber & Michael Faure (Eds.), Disaster Law, Vol. xiii, 2010.
      In general, in the law and economics literature, four types of legislative reactions to disasters are distinguished.8x For example, OECD, Catastrophic Risks and Insurance, 2005; Transboundary Risk Management, in Joanne Linnerooth-Bayer, Ragnar E. Lofstedt & Gunnar Sjostedt (Eds.), 2001; Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci & Michael G. Faure, The Economics of Disaster Relief, 37, Law & Pol’y., 180, 2015. The first one is where many governments do nothing structurally, but the victims generally rely on liability rules of tort law and social security already in place. The second one is government ad hoc charity or funds with fiscal allocation paid by the taxpayer’s money. The third one is the insurance coverage (usually first-party insurance) for victims. The last one is a public-private partnership (‘PPP’), whereby the government facilitates private insurance and/or acts as reinsurer to support private insurance.
      These solutions are quite diverging, and differ among many different legal regimes. For example, France introduced insurance for disaster coverage in 1982, whilst a government disaster fund still exists in Austria. Based on the current discussion in the law and economic literature, this article tries to explore the optimal compensation mechanism from a timing framework. Corresponding to a repetitive circle of disaster management as preventionresponserecovery,9x Kristian Cedervall Lauta, Disaster Law, Vol. 8, 2015. we assess the ex ante (before the disaster occurs), during (emergency response during a disaster) and ex post (after the disaster) compensation mechanisms.
      Ex ante is often regarded as the best way of victim protection and compensation, since it could reduce the damages caused by disasters and may even make compensation unnecessary.10x Michael Faure, Towards Effective Compensation for Victims of Natural Catastrophes in Developing Countries, in Michael Faure & Andri Wibisana (Eds.), Regulating Disasters, Climate Change and Environmental Harm: Lessons from the Indonesian Experience, 244 , 2013. Insurance is often regarded as the typical ex ante mechanism. Disaster insurance transforms ex post liability and damages into ex ante costs (premiums),11x Omri Ben-Shahar & Kyle D. Logue, Outsourcing Regulation: How Insurance Reduces Moral Hazard, 111, Mich. L. Rev., 197, 233, 2011. and could contribute to disaster prevention and mitigation through, e.g. providing incentives for potential victims to escape from risk exposure.12x Goetz von Peter et al., Unmitigated Disasters? New Evidence on the Macroeconomic Cost of Natural Catastrophes, 394, BIS Working Papers, 4, 16, 2012.
      During efforts are carried out when a state of emergency is declared. Emergency relief is popular practice as during mechanism. It is often supplied by the government in the immediate aftermath of a disaster, such as providing shelter, food, medical assistance and direct payment to victims.13x See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 181. This type of government intervention has a legitimate justification due to its public good nature, and few private parties have incentives to take such measures.14x Just as Logue points, “[A]ccording to modern law-and-economics (‘L&E’) orthodoxy, the primary—maybe even the only—legitimate justification for government regulation is to correct a market failure.” See Kyle D. Logue, In Praise of (Some) Ex Post Regulation: A Response to Professor Galle, 69, Vand. L. Rev., en Banc 97, 2016.
      Ex post happens after the state of emergency is over, and its goal is to compensate victims’ personal and property damages and return the conditions to those had the disaster never occurred.15x Herman B. Leonard & Arnold M. Howitt, Acting in Time against Disasters: A Comprehensive Risk-Management Framework, in Howard Kunreuther & Michael Useem (Eds.), Learning from Catastrophes: Strategies for Reaction and Response, 18-41, 2010. A government fund and recovery programme (also called charity by government) is a well-known ex post mechanism for disaster victims. Besides these government-provided compensation programmes, the liability rule of tort law is also considered as an incentive-based ex post mechanism.16x See Logue, supra note 14, at 122. However, liability rules can basically only apply in cases of technological disasters where a liable tortfeasor can be identified.17x Michael G. Faure, In the Aftermath of the Disaster: Liability and Compensation Mechanisms as Tools to Reduce Disaster Risks, 52, Stan. J. Int’l L., 95, 114-115, 2016. Where no tortfeasor is at hand in the case of natural disasters, victims often turn to government for compensation eventually. Correspondingly, politicians often participate in a race to provide ex post funds and recovery due to huge political benefits.18x Ben Depoorter, Horizontal Political Externalities: The Supply and Demand of Disaster Management, 56, Duke L.J., 101, 2006.
      According to the law and economic literature, government compensation is criticized for leading to an oversupply ex post and undersupply (investments in prevention) ex ante.19x Ibid., at 104. There is a developing consensus that under particular conditions, ex ante insurance is a preferred compensation mechanism,20x George Priest, The Government, the Market and the Problem of Catastrophic Loss, 12, J. Risk Uncertain., 221, 1996; Howard Kunreuther, Mitigating Disaster Losses through Insurance, 12, J. Risk Uncertain., 171, 1996. and ex post compensation could be substituted by less costly ex ante measures.21x See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 180. Most of the preventive measures aiming at disaster risk reduction can obviously be taken by the government. The government can, e.g. build dikes and organize a system of levies in view of an effective water management after a hurricane. But potential victims can also take preventive measures. They can, first of all, take a siting decision in an area which is not prone to flooding; and within the dwellings, measures can be taken, e.g. to put electrical equipment and valuables in the attic, rather than in the cellar. Since the government intervention can be divided between the during efforts and the ex post efforts, government efforts should, in fact, focus on both. Emergency relief by the government has advantages as that relief has a public good character and will usually not be provided by individuals. In addition, the government can support private ex ante insurance by acting as reinsurer of last resort, thus facilitating private disaster insurance.
      Following a comparative law and economic perspective, where the idea is to search for victim compensation at the lowest cost and at the same time provide incentives for disaster risk reduction,22x Robert B. Ahdieh, Reanalyzing Cost-Benefit Analysis: Toward a Framework of Function(s) and Form(s), 88, N.Y.U. L. Rev., 1983, 2013. our analysis indicates how a (combined) form of compensation mechanism could supply efficient incentives for prevention and mitigation23x Whereas prevention is aimed at reducing the probability that damage will occur in the event of a disaster, mitigation aims at reducing the extent of the damage once the disaster has occurred. and be provided at the lowest costs and thus realize welfare maximization. The remainder of this article is set up as follows. After this introduction (Section A), Section B describes the evolution of our understanding on disasters and introduces principles of fair and efficient compensation. Section C explains why the government intervenes in disaster compensation and how it can intervene fairly and efficiently. A distinction is drawn between the during efforts (emergency relief) and ex post efforts (ad hoc recovery and fund). Section D argues that where the government cannot provide efficient compensation ex post, insurance may do so ex ante. Then, in the next Section (Section E), as an optimal approach, the structure and the role of the PPP are discussed. These discussions include whether government intervention is needed to facilitate insurance work adequately, and what is the role for both the government and private insurance. Section F brings the article to a close with a few concluding remarks.

    • B Understanding Disasters and the Principles of Victim Compensation

      I The Understanding on Disasters

      Before discussing how to manage disaster risk and how to compensate victims, it is necessary to address the question what a disaster is, since which mechanism will be the optimal depends to some extent on the nature of the disaster.24x See Faure, supra note 17, at 99.
      The contemporary understanding of the disaster moves to ‘acts of the social (humankind)’ and believes the cause of disaster is neither God nor nature (at least not alone).25x Lauta, supra note 9. Two sub-conceptions ‘risk’ and ‘vulnerability’ are tied to the understanding of disaster as an act of the social.26x Ibid., at 36. The question how to address disaster then becomes how to control the risk and reduce the vulnerability to disasters. Victims of disasters no longer accept the old adagium (proverb) ‘the law lies where it falls’, but argue the social system’s inability to manage disasters. According to the paradigm theory,27x Thomas Kuhn, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, 1970. our understanding of disasters evolved from the first disaster-paradigm ‘acts of God’, to the second ‘acts of nature’, and to the current ‘acts of the social (humankind)’.28x Lauta, supra note 9, at 14-22; Frank Furedi, The Changing Meaning of Disaster, 39, Area, 482, 2007.
      A common distinction of disasters is made among natural disasters (e.g. earthquakes, floods and tsunamis), man-made disasters (e.g. wars, terrorism and explosions) and socioeconomic disasters (e.g. financial crisis and severe sociopolitical fragmentation). However, such distinctions become less important since there are ‘many causes but one clear truth: disasters are not natural’.29x Ben Wisner, Ilan Kelman & J.C. Gaillard, Hazard, Vulnerability, Capacity, Risk and Participation, in Alejandro et al. (Eds.), Disaster Management, International Lessons in Risk Reduction, Response, and Recovery, 14, 2014. Whilst the causes of disasters may be natural, their outcome, or at least the severity of that outcome, are not necessarily so. Under this circumstance, it is reasonable to predict that victims will claim compensation, especially when the harm is large and hits thousands of victims. Some politicians will not be able to resist the temptation of compensating the victims, due to the large political rewards that compensation provides.30x See Depoorter, supra note 18, at 101-125; Kip W. Viscusi, The Hold-Up Problem. Why It Is Urgent to Rethink the Economics of Disaster Insurance Protection, in Erwann Michel-Kerjan & Paul Slovic (Eds.), The Irrational Economist. Making Decisions in a Dangerous World, 142-148, 2010.

      II Guiding Principles of Compensation

      Since there are different types of mechanism to compensate disaster victims, how to assess, evaluate and compare these mechanisms is a core issue. The literature provides valuable insights to develop a few guiding principles.
      The first principle is that a victim compensation programme should accord with efficiency standards. These efficiency standards include, inter alia, the following: first, the compensation mechanism should provide potential victims with incentives to prevent damages and reduce losses since prevention is always more important than cure.31x Michael Faure, Liability and Compensation for Damage Resulting from CO2 Storage Sites, 40, Wm. & Mary Envtl. L. & Pol’y Rev., 387, 437, 2016. Second, the compensation mechanism should apply disaster risk differentiation, which prevents shifting of risks and losses from a collectivity, and make those who contribute larger to the risk pay more.32x Michael Faure, A Multilayered Approach to Cover Damages Caused by Offshore Facilities, 33, Va. Envtl. L.J. 357, 403, 2015. Risk differentiation relates, in the first place, to tortfeasors (e.g. an operator of a nuclear facility) who expose individuals and society at risk. But risk differentiation can also apply to the victims and their respective vulnerability to the disaster. If a compensation programme (e.g. for flooding) applies risk differentiation, it will provide incentives for prevention, risk reduction and mitigation of damage.33x Howard Kunreuther, The Case for Comprehensive Disaster Insurance, 11, J. L. & Econ., 133-163, 1968; Richard A. Epstein, Catastrophe Responses to Catastrophe Risks, 12, J. Risk Uncertain., 287-308, 1996. Third, the compensation mechanism should be operated at the lowest administrative cost.34x Michael Faure, Climate Change Adaption and Compensation, in Jonathan Verschuuren (Ed.), Research Handbook on Climate Change Adaptation Law, 114-115, 2013. Fourth, the compensation programme should ensure timely payments to victims since the delays in paying can increase the suffering of victims.35x See Steven Garber, Designing Compensation Programs for Individuals and Households after Man-Made and Natural Disasters in the United States, 45-46, 2016.
      Of course, there may be conflicts in trying to achieve this efficiency principle, especially in cases where it would be impossible for potential victims to invest in disaster risk reduction. For example, potential victims of flooding in Bangladesh could hardly be blamed for living in a flood-prone area, as they may simply have no other choice in practice.36x See Faure, supra note 34, at 115. In other cases, some low-income families may be seriously exposed to, e.g. hurricane risks and would thus (in view of efficient risk differentiation) have to pay relatively high insurance premiums which may be unaffordable to them. Some solutions have been suggested, e.g. providing vouchers to low-income families to pay the insurance premiums on the condition that they would take measures aiming at disaster risk reduction.37x See, e.g. Carolyn Kousky & Howard Kunreuther, Addressing Affordability in the National Flood Insurance Program, Resources for the Future and Wharton Risk Management and Decision Process Center, August 2013.

    • C During and Ex Post Government-Provided Victim Compensation Mechanisms

      I Why Government Compensation for Victims?

      Why government should consider compensating victims is a preliminary question that has to be addressed before we discuss what kind of government mechanisms should be used. It has been argued that many have the normative belief that providing disaster compensation is one of the principal functions of government.38x See Priest, supra note 20, at 235. Disasters often lead to a complete disruption of society. For example, as a result of a big nuclear blast or a devastating earthquake, half of a city might not be used anymore. Many victims are homeless, and the banks have mortgages that are worth nothing anymore. The potential side effects for the whole society (including the economy and financial system) can be huge. Government compensation can fulfill an important function to bring victims back to some extent of normality.39x Ibid. Moreover, leaving victims without relief and compensation is incompatible with notions of solidarity, especially in the European Union (EU) welfare states.40x Reimund Schwarze & Gert Wagner, In the Aftermath of Dresden: New Directions in German Flood Insurance, 29, Geneva Pap. Risk Insur., 154, 154-168, 2004. Third, government compensation for victims is providing public goods in case of disasters. Disasters are different from an accident suffered by an individual victim. Dealing with large-scale damage losses is a typical public good that is not sufficiently provided through private actors. Compared with private actors, the government could channel capital quickly after catastrophes since it can raise money by issuing debt or government bonds, or tax (also a form of cross entire population risk diversification), or diversifying the risks to future generations (a form of cross time diversification).41x David M. Cutler & Richard J. Zeckhauser, Reinsurance for Catastrophes and Cataclysms, in Kenneth A. Froot (Ed.), The Financing of Catastrophe Risk, 258-259, 1999; Howard Kunreuther & Erwann Michel-Kerjan, Challenges for Terrorism Risk Insurance in the United States, 18, J. Econ. Persp., 201, 2004. By providing compensation to thousands of victims, it could help restore public trust in the government.42x Levmore & Logue, supra note 4, at 310.
      Although the significant losses and damages caused by disasters leading to serious political and economic instability justify and require an efficient compensation system, government compensation for victims of disasters is principally debated. Moreover, questions also arise concerning the effectiveness of compensation in specific cases. Generally, the government prefers to provide compensation ex post rather than ex ante for political visibility due to news coverage.43x Lisa Grow Sun, Disaster Mythology and the Law, 96, Cornell L. Rev., 1131, 2011. Empirical research has shown that half of all disaster compensation funding by the U.S. Federal Emergency Management Agency (FEMA) is driven by politics rather than by altruism.44x Thomas A. Garrett, Thomas L. Marsh & Maria I. Marshall, Political Allocation of US Agriculture Disaster Payments in the 1990s, 26, Int. Rev. Law Econ., 143-161, 2006. That, therefore, raises the question why particular victims, more particularly those suffering from disasters, should receive a preferential treatment compared to others. This may violate the equality principle. Kaplow suggested that what the government should worry about is the incentives for disaster prevention and deterrence,45x Louis Kaplow, Incentives and Government Relief for Risk, 4, J. Risk Uncertain., 167-175, 1991. rather than redistributing taxpayers’ money to victims of disasters.
      This is why government compensation for disaster victims has a poor reputation, and is generally criticized in the law and economic literature.46x Richard Epstein even calls this form of compensation: “Catastrophic responses to catastrophic risk” (Epstein, supra note 33. However, government compensation mechanism takes different forms in different stages of disaster management. We try to carve out a broader scope for government compensation and make a distinction between during relief efforts (at time 0, meaning during the disaster strikes and the immediate aftermath) and ex post recovery efforts (at time +1, meaning the reasonable time after the disaster).47x See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 183-184. The general critics of government intervention apply to ex post recovery, but not to the during relief efforts. The following sub-sections expand the analysis of during versus ex post efforts and explore their fundamental differences.

      II During Government Relief

      1. Pro

      The during government relief has received less attention than traditionally ex post recovery, which is in the law and economics literature often contrasted with ex ante mechanisms.48x For example, Edward M. Iacobucci, Michael J. Trebilcock & Huma Haider, Economic Shocks: Defining a Role for Government, 2001; Brian Galle, in Praise of Ex Ante Regulation, 68 Vand. L. Rev., 1715, 2015; see Logue, supra note 14, at 122. During government relief refers to an immediate and effective response after a disaster, and consists of medical assistance, food, money and other basic living necessities.49x See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 185. Take the United States, e.g. federal relief efforts include “coordinating necessary decisions, support[ing] search and rescue efforts, and […] provid[ing] public health, medical and mental health support at casualty evacuation points and refugee shelters”. See Report: Disaster Evacuation. Cong Bea, Research Serve; Disaster Evacuation and Displacement Policy: Issues for Congress 2005, 2-3, available at: www.everycrsreport.com/files/20060817_RS22235_cc0ebce1cf39f6a7c5f7d52b106084bc40ca427e.pdf. In contrast to ex post recovery (at time +1), the during government relief could be basically regarded as the emergency relief (at time 0). Like the ‘golden hour’ in emergency medical services, there is also the so-called first 72 hours after a disaster.50x Homeland Security Today, Funding the first 72 hours, available at: https://www.hstoday.us/channels/fema/funding-the-first-72-hours/. The first 72 hours are critical, since, e.g. in the case of an earthquake, the chance of finding survivors dramatically decreases after that period.51x Jacob Hunter, Why the First 72 Hours After a Disaster Are Critical, available at: www.primalsurvivor.net/why-the-first-72-hours-after-a-disaster-are-critical/. Therefore, there are strong reasons for the during government relief.
      First, during government relief has a public good character since thousands of victims need rapid compensation after the unannounced strikes. Since private actors may have no incentives and lack the capacity to take emergency measures due to the large scale and the suddenness of relief activities, the government may be the best placed to do so.52x Michael Trebilcock & Ronald J. Daniels, Rationales and Instruments for Government Intervention, in Ronald J. Daniels, Donald F. Kettl & Howard Kunreuther (Eds.), On Risk and Disaster: Lessons from Hurricane Katrina, 89-107, 2006. Second, the government has the capacity to provide relief through the mobilization of national coordinated efforts and the pooling of significant resources.53x See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 186. Third, relief is potentially damage-limiting and has a positive ex post effect. It reduces the immediate damages that will have to be paid for either by the victim or through the government recovery efforts. As we discussed previously, the government prefers to oversupply recovery due to the news-sensitive effect of disaster. The during relief could reduce recovery costs. It also alleviates, to some extent, the dilution of ex ante prevention incentives since fewer funds will be drawn to ex post recovery.54x Ibid., at 199. Although during relief is therefore generally preferred, at least compared to ex post recovery, difficulties may remain in judging the effectiveness of the during relief. The following case study concerning Hurricane Katrina can illustrate that.

      2. A Case Study of During Government Relief

      Of course, there is sometimes also criticism on the way in which the government provides during relief in particular cases. Relief is, in some cases, not provided in a timely manner or not in an effective way. Take the example of the failure of FEMA’s performance during Hurricane Katrina.55x William F. Shughart, Katrinanomics: The Politics and Economics of Disaster Relief, 127, Public Choice, 31-53, 2006. This is generally not considered the failure of government relief as such, but rather an example of a failure concerning leadership with respect to government relief.56x Ibid. The contrary example – the success of the Chinese Government during the 2008 Sichuan Earthquake has shown the positive role of during relief.
      In 2008, the earthquake, magnitude 8.0, struck the Sichuan Province in China. The losses exceeded $ 100 billion and it caused 69,277 deaths.57x Hu Jintao, Address on the National Earthquake Relief Summary Commendation Conference [Zai Quanguo Kangzhen Jiuzai Zongjie Biaozhang Dahui Shangde Jianghua], 2008. The scale and suddenness of disaster damages demand immense resources and funds in a short time. The central government appropriated $ 83 million for relief efforts on the night that the earthquake occurred; within one week, the central government supplied more than $ 400 million in earthquake relief;58x Xinhua News Agency, Central Government Appropriated $ 400 Million to Earthquake Relief, 15 May 2008, available at: http://news.xinhuanet.com/newscenter/2008-05/15/content_8180172.htm. within four months, the government had created an emergency disaster relief fund in the amount of about $ 11 billion.59x Peijun Shi & Xin Zhang, Chinese Mechanism against Catastrophe Risk – The Experience of Great Sichuan Earthquake, 28, J. Tsinghua Univ. (Philosophy and Social Sciences), 96-113, 2013.
      China’s during government relief efforts can be categorized into two aspects: (1) emergency response, including rescuing victims, providing medical treatment to injured people, providing food and shelter for victims, etc. and (2) direct payment to victims.60x Office of the National Commission for Disaster Reduction, P.R. China, China’s Natural Disaster Risk Management, in Improving the Assessment of Disaster Risks to Strengthen Financial Resilience, 121-131, A Special Joint G20 Publication by the Government of Mexico and the World Bank, 2012. For per person, the government supplied a three-month temporary living subsidy, which was approximately RMB 10 yuan (about US $ 2 in 2008) plus 0.5 kilogram of bread every day to earthquake-affected people; for per family, government provided each victim’s family with a lump sum payment of RMB 5,000 yuan (about US $ 900 in 2008).61x Jiang Lingling et al., People’s Republic of China: Providing Emergency Response to Sichuan Earthquake, Technical Assistance Consultant’s Report to Ministry of Civil Affairs, P.R. China and Asian Development Bank, 2008. The government offered additional compensation to the injured, orphans, lonely elderly and the handicapped with RMB 600 yuan (about US $ 100 in 2008) per month. Moreover, for the seriously injured, the government provided RMB 28,000 (about US $ 4,600 in 2008) medical subsidies; for the minor wounded, their medical treatment was free of charge (paid by the government).62x Ibid.
      According to three surveys conducted after the earthquake, during government relief has been viewed as successful by the public.63x Kristin Dalen, Hedda Flatø, Liu Jing & Zhang Huafeng, Recovering from the Wenchuan Earthquake. Living Conditions and Development in Disaster Areas 2008-2011, Fafo-Report 2012, 39, 2012. It is regarded as both ‘close and timely’.64x Ibid. The reasons why the during government relief was considered to be effective in China are the following. First, the Chinese government has a relatively strong financial capability to undertake disaster relief since China has grown to be the second largest economy in the world.65x Barry Naughton, China’s Economy: Complacency, Crisis & the Challenge of Reform, 143, Daedalus, 14-25, 2014. Second, the Chinese central government could require some provinces which have stronger economic power to donate 1% of their fiscal revenue from the preceding year to assist disaster-affected areas.66x Yi-Ming Wei, Ju-Liang Jin & Qiong Wang, Impacts of Natural Disasters and Disaster Risk Management in China: The Case of China’s Experience in Wenchuan Earthquake, in Yasuyuki Sawada & Sothea Oum (Eds.), Economic and Welfare Impacts of Disasters in East Asia and Policy Responses, 641-675, 2012. This is a type of an intergovernmental national ‘pooling’ of the catastrophe risk. Third, the Chinese government could mobilize military power for emergency disaster relief.67x Jian Zhang, The Military and Disaster Relief in China: Trends, Drivers and Implications, in Minako Sakai et al. (Eds.), Disaster Relief in the Asia Pacific: Agency and Resilience, 79-80, 2014. Fourth, the Chinese government enjoys high levels of trust from residents in disaster areas since a lack of trust would undermine the credibility and stability of the government relief, and lead to inefficiency, unrest, or even failure.68x Dalen et al., supra note 63. Of course, one has to be relativistic about the fact that the public praises the Chinese government for the effectiveness of the disaster relief. They were also largely the beneficiaries of this during relief, so their opinion may be biased. However, generally during relief does not create the same type of moral hazard as ex post recovery,69x In the sense that ex post recovery does negatively affect the incentives to invest in disaster risk reduction. The same is not the case with during relief. See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8. so the most important question is whether the funds do indeed effectively reach the targeted goals.

      III Ex Post Government Recovery

      Ex post government recovery often takes two different forms, either through ad hoc charity or via a structural fund. These ex post programs can be found in many countries. Countries like Germany, Italy, the Netherlands and Sweden usually provide ad hoc compensation to victims, whilst Austria and Belgium have a structural compensation fund.70x Tola Amodu, Michael Faure & Ton Hartlief (Eds.), Financial Compensation for Victims of Catastrophes: A Comparative Legal Approach, 2006. These two solutions share many similarities, and the major distinction is whether the compensation decision is made case by case, depending on each disaster’s damages.71x Michael Faure, Financial Compensation for Victims of Catastrophes: A Law and Economics Perspective, 29, L. & Pol’y., 339, 353, 2007. Although the government in different jurisdictions provides generous ex post recovery due to political considerations in practice,72x Alberto Monti & Filippo Andrea Chiaves, Italy, in Michael Faure & Ton Hartlief (Eds.), Financial Compensation for Victims of Catastrophes: A Comparative Legal Approach, 145-194, 2006. the critics to and disadvantages of this ex post government recovery are widely discussed.
      First, ex post government recovery provides negative ex ante incentives for prevention, and result in a less-safe environment and higher death tolls.73x Justin Pidot, Deconstructing Disaster, 2013, BYU L. Rev., 213, 2013. Take, e.g. Hurricane Katrina. On the one hand, various government authorities participated in the race to provide recovery over $ 100 million ex post;74x See Depoorter, supra note 18, at 101. however, there was a lack of investment in prevention and a lack of emergency planning prior to the disaster.75x Oliver Houck, Can We Save New Orleans? 19, Tul. Envtl. L. J., 1, 2006; William L. Waugh Jr., The Disaster That Was Katrina, Natural Hazards Observer, 30, 2005 On the other hand, it causes the charity hazard of victims, which induces the dilemma that more government recovery may cause more disaster losses because people are less likely to take precaution and prevention measures.76x Paul A. Raschky & Hannelore Weck-Hannemann, Charity Hazard – A Real Hazard to Natural Disaster Insurance? 7, Envtl. Hazards, 321, 2007. Helpless and uninsured victims are more vulnerable to disasters and, therefore, require more ex post aid, which, in turn, makes the disaster more salient and politicians more eager to stage a rescue.77x See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 182.
      Second, ex post government recovery is increasingly insufficient for the growing needs and may not be fit for purpose, due to the pressure on aid budgets and the delay in the disbursement.78x Theodore Talbot & Owen Barder, Payouts for Perils: Why Disaster Aid Is Broken, and How Catastrophe Insurance Can Help to Fix It, CGD Policy Paper 087, Washington, D.C: Center for Global Development, 2016, available at:. www.cgdev.org/sites/default/files/payouts-perils-why-disaster-aid-broken-and-how-catastrophe-insurance-can-help-fix-it-0.pdf. Government funding is usually disbursed annually, which creates a growing mismatch between needs and financing. Empirical research also found that government aid flows are not always associated with victims’ needs.79x Christopher B. Barrett, Does Food Aid Stabilize Food Availability?, 49, Econ. Dev. Cult. Change, 335-349, 2001; Polly J. Diven, The Domestic Determinants of US Food Aid Policy, 26, Food Policy, 455-474, 2001.
      Third, political-driven recovery puts too much weight on the news-sensitive problems and hence diverts resources away from humanitarian compensation.80x See Sun, supra note, at 45. For instance, an empirical study shows a correlation between elections and realized ex post government payment: “disasters occurring in election years attract more ex post funding relative to disasters in other years”.81x Erwann Michel-Kerjan, Haven’t You Switched to Risk Management 2.0 Yet?, in Erwann Michel-Kerjan & Paul Slovic (Eds.), The Irrational Economist: Making Decisions in a Dangerous World, 41-46, 2010. An oversupply of ex post recovery is nearly unavoidable since it allocates large political rewards to politicians.82x See Depoorter, supra note 18, at 101. This obviously violates the equality principle since victims who suffer disaster in the election year are luckier than victims of disasters occurring in other years.83x Richard Zeckhauser, The Economics of Catastrophes, 12, J. Risk Uncertain., 134, 1996.

    • D Ex ante Insurance Mechanism for Victim Compensation

      The previous section showed that ex post government compensation mechanisms dilute residents’ prevention incentives and create the mentioned charity hazard. Conversely, an ex ante insurance mechanism could provide positive incentives to victims for disaster reduction. However, potential victims’ reliance on government prevents them from purchasing insurance.84x Levmore & Logue, supra note 4, at 281. Just as Gollier has argued, ‘solidarity kills market insurance’.85x Christian Gollier (Ed.), Some Aspects of the Economics of Catastrophe Risk Insurance, in Catastrophic Risks and Insurance, 13-30, 2005. An empirical research on crop insurance in the Netherlands has shown that due to government disaster compensation, insureds’ incentive to purchase insurance would be severely undermined.86x Marcel A.P.M. van Asseldonk, Miranda P.M. Meuwissen & Ruud B.M. Huirne, Belief in Disaster Relief and the Demand for a Public-Private Insurance Program, 24, Rev. Agric. Econ., 196, 2002.
      However, the role of insurance in compensating victims has been emphasized in recent years. Take Belgium, e.g. which once provided compensation through a structured fund to victims. Since 2003, Belgium has moved to a system of mandatory insurance, substantially reducing the role of the compensation fund in compensating victims.87x Veronique Bruggeman, Michael G. Faure & Miriam Haritz, Remodeling Reparation: Changes in the Compensation of Victims of Natural Catastrophes in Belgium and the Netherlands, 35, Disasters, 766, 767, 780, 2011. Following Belgium and France’s comprehensive disaster insurance in covering disaster risks, there might be a transition moving from ex post government recovery to ex ante insurance in the Europe.88x See Faure, supra note 10, at 442-444. There is no formal EU intervention as far as the compensation for victims of disasters is concerned.89x There is, however, an EU Solidarity Fund to deal with major natural disasters, as that provides help to member states rather than directly to victims. See Regulation 661/2014 amending Council Regulation 2012/2002 establishing the European Solidarity Fund, OJ L 189 of 27 June 2014. As a result, EU member states, in principle, decide on their own how to organize a system of compensation for disaster victims. That explains the wide variety that can be observed. However, the Belgian and French insurance system has been praised by law and economics scholars, and promoted for a much wider scale;90x Michel Cannarsa, Fabien Lafay & Olivier Moréteau, France, in Michael Faure & Ton Hartlief (Eds.), Financial Compensation for Victims of Catastrophes: A Comparative Legal Approach, 81-118, 2006; Howard Kunreuther, Has the Time Come for Comprehensive Natural Disaster Insurance? in Ronald J. Daniels, Donald F. Kettle & Howard Kunreuther (Eds.), On Risk and Disaster: Lessons from Hurricane Katrina, 175-201, 2006. whilst in other states, like the Netherlands, the lack of a comprehensive ex ante insurance system is severely criticized.91x Bruggeman et al., supra note 87, at 767.

      I Ex ante Insurance verse Ex Post Government Recovery

      1. Incentives for Disaster Risk Reduction

      People reacting to financial incentives is one of the basic starting points of law and economic analysis.92x Robert Cooter & Thomas Ulen, Law & Economics, 4, 5th ed., 2008. The first benchmark for the comparison and evaluation of the optimal mechanism is whether it is possible to provide positive incentives for disaster risk reduction and adopt preventive measures. When exposing potential victims to the financial consequences of disasters, that may affect their decisions to avoid risk and losses. Compared to ex post government recovery, the major advantage of ex ante insurance is that it could provide positive incentives for potential victims to invest in risk reduction and preventive measures.93x Howard Kunreuther, Erwann Michel-Kerjan & Nicola Ranger, Insuring Future Climate Catastrophes, 118, Climate Change, 339, 2013; see Kunreuther, supra note 33, at 133. Although investing in disaster risk reduction is, in principle, possible with all kinds of disasters, the possibilities for victims to reduce risk ex ante may well vary according to time and place, as was indicated above. Especially in developing countries where, e.g. a location choice in an area which is not prone to disaster risk is often simply not an option. The payment of an insurance premium before the disaster makes the insured aware of the vulnerability to the disaster. This has a positive impact on their behaviour.94x See Faure, supra note 17, at 101; see Priest, supra note 20, at 221-225 (arguing that private insurance is able, via the control of the moral hazard by insurers, to provide incentives for mitigation of disaster risks). This rationale certainly applies to natural disasters in areas that are particularly prone, e.g. to flooding or earthquakes. The situation may be different, however, with disasters that are so grave that they occur once in a lifetime. In that particular case, it may be more difficult to assume that those potential disasters could shape the behaviour of individuals or governments.
      To the contrary, ex post government recovery fails to alert potential victims to the disaster consequences, and may thus negatively affect their decision to invest in mitigation measures. Moreover, in certain cases, due to certain public and institutional biases, preventive measures may be higher than the costs (the costs invested in the prevention of terror attacks may be higher than other death-causing risks such as car accidents or non-efficient health services).
      Besides exposing potential victims to the financial consequences of disasters, it is equally important to relate the victims’ financial contribution (in insurance: the premium) to the extent to which the victim is exposed to risk. In other words, risk differentiation should be applied.95x Faure, supra note 17, at 101-102. The victims exposed to more risk should, therefore, pay a higher financial contribution (higher premium) and vice versa. This differentiation of risk can positively affect victims’ incentives for prevention. Ex ante insurance could execute such risk differentiation before the disaster because the insured who are exposed to more risk have to pay higher premiums. Insurance in that manner contributes to risk awareness. Insurance solutions are preferred to undifferentiated lump sum payments to victims by the government. The problem with lump sum government compensation is that, in principle, individuals who posed no risk and those with high risk receive the same payments.96x See Epstein, supra note 33, at 297; see Kaplow, supra note 45, at 167 (holding that ex post government compensation can negatively affect incentives for prevention). In that way, government compensation negatively affects the incentives for disaster risk reduction as well as for mitigation of damages. Since the capital of government compensation generally comes from all taxpayers, it might further violate distributional justice because the higher risk residents, such as those living in a flood-prone area, may simply freeride on all the taxpayers.97x Anne Gron & Alan O. Sykes, Terrorism and Insurance Markets: A Role for the Government as Insurer?, 36, Indiana L. Rev., 447, 447-463, 2003.

      2. Administrative Cost

      The second benchmark is whether the compensation mechanism could be operated at the lowest administrative cost. Ex post government recovery is sometimes regarded as the ‘catastrophic responses to catastrophic risk,’98x See Epstein, supra note 33, at 287. due to its higher administrative cost including, but not limited to, salaries and wages paid to programme administrators, claim processors and auditors; costs related to develop claims and other forms for applying compensation; fees on communication with public; etc.99x See Garber, supra note 35, at 46. Compared to government, ex ante insurance is praised due to its advantages of lower administrative costs and higher efficiency as a result of using competitive markets.100x Dwight Jaffe & Thomas Russell, Catastrophe Insurance, Capital Markets, and Uninsured Risks, 62, J. Risk Insur., 225-230, 1997; Howard Kunreuther, Mitigating Disaster Losses through Insurance, 12, J. Risk Uncertain., 171-187, 1996; Veronique Bruggeman, Michael Faure & Karine Fiore, The Government as Reinsurer of Catastrophe Risks?, 35, Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. Issues Pract., 369-390, 2010. Therefore, ex post government recovery should and could be substituted by cheaper ex ante insurance purchased before the disaster. Against efficient management, there is, of course, a profit that insurance companies anticipate to make as a result of covering individuals against the disaster risk. Insurance purchasers are expected to finance that profit. To some extent, those profits made by insurance companies could outweigh the higher administrative costs related to ex post government compensation, although, generally, private insurance companies will have better incentives for cost reduction than do governments.101x Although there have been some exceptional cases of disaster cover via the government at lower costs than the market. See on this case of so-called efficient monopolies Thomas von Ungern-Sternberg, The Limits of Competition: Housing Insurance in Switzerland, 40, Eur. Econ. Rev., 1113-1114, 1996; Véronique Bruggeman, Michael Faure & Tobias Heldt, Insurance against Catastrophe: Government Stimulation of Insurance Markets for Catastrophic Events, 23, Duke Envtl. L. Pol’y Forum, 212-218, 2012.

      II The Role of Insurance for Victim Compensation and Disaster Risk Reduction

      1. Moral Hazard Control

      Some may argue against ex ante insurance due to the problem of moral hazard. Moral hazard is the tendency of insureds from vulnerable areas to exercise less care to avoid losses than they would if insurers did not cover the losses.102x Kenneth S. Abraham, Insurance Law and Regulation, 7, 5th ed., 2010. The statement that insurance could control moral hazard seems counterintuitive. Indeed, in much of the literature, insurance is seen as antithetical to risk reduction.103x For example, Bengt Hölmstrom, Moral Hazard and Observability, 10, Bell J. Econ.,74, 1979; Tom Baker, On the Genealogy of Moral Hazard, 75, Tex. L. Rev., 237, 1996. However, compared to the government, insurance is better at controlling and reducing moral hazard through using technical tools stealthily.104x Carol Heimer, Insuring More, Ensuring Less: The Costs and Benefits of Private Regulation through Insurance, in Tom Baker & Jonathan Simon (Eds.), Embracing Risk: The Changing Culture of Insurance and Responsibility, 117-145, 2002.
      These technical tools, which almost all insurers use to one degree or another to control moral hazard, include risk-based pricing, contract design (e.g. limits, deductibles, copayments and exclusions), loss prevention services, etc.105x See Shahar & Logue, supra note 11, at 111; Tom Baker & Rick Swedloff, Regulation by Liability Insurance: From Auto to Lawyers Professional Liability, 60, UCLA L. Rev., 1412, 2013; ShauhinTalesh, Legal Intermediaries: How Insurance Companies Construct the Meaning of Compliance with Anti-Discrimination Laws, 37, L. & Pol’y., 209, 2015. Risk-based pricing is just the practice for the application of risk differentiation, since it offers lower premium to insureds adopting mitigation measures and higher premium to riskier insureds.106x Howard Kunreuther, Reducing Losses from Catastrophe Risks through Long-Term Insurance and Mitigation, 75, Social Res., 905, 916, 2008. A deductible as a form of contract design could reduce moral hazard because it prevents potential victims from shielding themselves entirely.107x See Baker & Swedloff, supra note 105, at 1420-1421. Insurers could provide loss-prevention services due to their professional skills in risk management, such as retrofitting of houses against windstorms to induce potential victims to avoid losses.108x Swenja Surminski, The Role of Insurance in Reducing Direct Risk: the Case of Flood Insurance, 7, Int. Rev. Envtl. Res. Econ., 241, 264, 2013.
      In sum, through offering effective incentives, applying technical tools, and monitoring policyholders’ behaviour, ex ante insurance has the capacity to control moral hazard of insureds, promote policyholders’ cost-effective actions and thus work as an efficient compensation mechanism.

      2. Barriers to the Development of Disaster Insurance

      First-party insurance has the potential to play a positive role in disaster victim compensation, but it has done relatively little so far in practice.109x Sean B. Hecht, Climate Change and the Transformation of Risk: Insurance Matters, 55, UCLA L. Rev., 1559, 1586, 2008. Insurers even retreated from underwriting catastrophic disasters and (partially) withdrew from such market.110x For example, in the United States, the biggest private insurance market in the world, after Hurricane Katrina in 2005, numerous insurance firms cut back their coverage in coastal areas. As of 2012, many catastrophe losses remained uninsured. See Swiss Re, Natural Catastrophes and Man-made Disasters in 2012: A Year of Extreme Weather Events in the US, 2013, available at:. https://www.swissre.com/institute/research/sigma-research/sigma-2013-02.html. Several barriers from both the supply side and the demand side prevent the development of disaster risk policies.
      For the supply side, the barriers include increased losses of disasters, short-run profit horizon of insurers and their directors and officers, and the insurability concern of catastrophes.111x Qihao He, Mitigation of Climate Change Risks and Regulation by Insurance: A Feasible Proposal for China, 43, B.C. Envtl. Aff. L. Rev., 319, 339, 2016. As a result, insurers actually do not have strong incentives to provide disaster coverage.
      For the demand side, many potential victims just do not purchase catastrophe insurance. Behavioural economics explains consumers’ anomalies due to the intuitive thinking bias112x Daniel Kahneman, Thinking, Fast and Slow, 20-21, 2011. and myopic loss aversion.113x Shlomo Benartzi & Richard Thaleer, Myopic Loss Aversion and the Equity Premium Puzzle, 110, Q. J. Econ., 73-92, 1995. Consumers just ignore such catastrophe risk because they believe ‘it will not happen to me’.114x Paul Slovic, Howard Kunreuther & Gilbert F. White, Decision Processes, Rationality and Adjustment to Natural Hazards, in Paul Slovic (Ed.), The Perception of Risk, 1-31, 2000. This attitude makes consumers underestimate the risks of being exposed in disasters and they will not purchase sufficient insurance coverage voluntarily.115x Farber & Faure, supra note 7, at xix. What is worse, counting on ex post government recovery following disasters, as we discussed in Section C, many victims choose not to purchase insurance, which is actually a rational choice rather than a bias.116x Howard Kunreuther, Mark V. Pauly & Stacey McMorrow, Insurance and Behavioral Economics: Improving Decisions in the Most Misunderstood Industry, 114-115, 2013. In other words, the insufficient demand for insurance may result from the ex post generosity of the government.117x Stephen Coate, Altruism, the Samaritan’s Dilemma, and Government Transfer Policy, 85, Am. Econ. Rev., 46-57, 1995.

    • E Public-Private Partnership for Victim Compensation

      By discussing government-provided compensation mechanisms, we noticed a mixed role of government intervention. On the one hand, during government relief corresponds, as was shown above in Section C II, with principles of efficient compensation. On the other hand, ex post government recovery provides, as shown in Section C III, negative incentives for disaster risk reduction.118x Steven Shavell, A General Rationale for a Governmental Role in the Relief of Large Risks, 49, J., Risk Uncertain., 213, 214, 2014. In Section D, it was concluded that ex ante insurance can, on the one hand, provide incentives for disaster risk reduction. On the other hand, disaster insurance may not emerge since insurers may be reluctant to provide cover and individuals exposed to risk may not realize that their situation could be improved through insurance. This justifies an intervention of the government to support disaster insurance. Potential victims lack sufficient demand for insurance. For some potential victims, it is the rational response since they count on ex post government recovery.119x Ibid., at 215. For some victims, it is irrational since they may largely underestimate the risk for low-probability losses.120x See Kunreuther et al., supra note 116, at 113-118.
      Therefore, a PPP, which could combine the merits of both government intervention and insurance, might be an optimal choice. Different approaches of those PPPs can be found in several countries.

      I Evaluating Different Approaches of PPP in Compensating Victims

      Since there is no unified definition of PPP, this word has been used under different circumstances and carries different meanings.121x Anthony E. Boardman, Carsten Greve & Graeme A. Hodge, Comparative Analyses of Infrastructure Public-Private Partnerships, 17, J. Comp. Policy Anal. Res. Pract., 441, 442, 2015. It has shifted from being a simple technique adopted by the government to enhance infrastructure development towards being a comprehensive policy preference at the heart of governance.122x A.J. Smith, Privatized Infrastructure: The Role of Government, 1999. In the field of disaster victim compensation, the attempts to develop PPPs generally can take three different forms.
      Under the first approach, insurers provide disaster risk coverage and compensate victims in the case of damages, whilst the government does not intervene in either direct insurance or reinsurance. The task of the government in this first model is to take administrative measures to facilitate and guarantee the independence of insurers’ operation, such as setting rules for buildings and land use and protecting the well-functioning competitive market. The old English flood insurance programme, the one that existed before the entry of the new Flood Re programme, in the United Kingdom, is a typical example. The United Kingdom’s private flood insurance scheme demonstrates how a large private insurance could work, and it was considered efficient.123x Michael Huber, Insurability and Regulatory Reform: Is the English Flood Insurance Regime Able to Adapt to Climate Change?, 29, Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. Issues Pract., 169-182, 2004. Flood Re was built on a gentleman’s agreement between the insurers and the government, whereby the government agreed to invest substantially in preventive measures to reduce flood risks and the insurers from their side agreed to provide cover. The challenge facing the United Kingdom, however, was how to keep it widely available and affordable, specifically to enable high-flood-risk households to obtain it at an affordable price, which is a main concern of the new Flood Re programme.124x The Flood Re model is loosely based on Pool Re, a reinsurance scheme for terrorism risks formed in 1993 in response to the threat posed by the Irish Republican Army and other terrorist activity. See Johanna Hjalmarsson & Mateusz Bek, Legislative and Regulatory Methodology and Approach: Developing Catastrophe Insurance in China, in Johanna Hjalmarsson & Dingjing Huang (Eds.), Insurance Law in China, 197, 2015. In recent years, the programme has also been challenged as the insurers considered that the government did not come up to its part of the deal, i.e. too few investments would have been made in flood prevention. Currently, the UK government has reformed building regulations, ensuring that residents are required to take disaster resilience/resistance measures.125x Flood Re, Incentivising Household Action on Flooding and Options for Using Incentives to Increase the Take- Up of Flood Resilience and Resistance Measures, 2018, available at: www.floodre.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/Flood-Re_Position-on-Incentives_SMF-report.pdf. In this first model, the cooperation is therefore relatively loose in the sense that it is the insurers that provide cover; the government, from its side, promises to take either public measures to prevent risks or to issue regulations aiming at disaster risk reduction.
      The second model seems to be the opposite of the first approach. In the second model, the government is the primary risk bearer for disaster, whilst private insurers only play an exclusively administrative role in running the programme.126x Peter Molk, The Government’s Role in Climate Change Insurance, 43, B.C. Envtl. Aff. L. Rev., 411, 424, 2016. This model has been developed within the National Flood Insurance Program (NFIP) in the United States. The NFIP was established according to the National Flood Insurance Act of 1968, in order to assume the flood risk and offer coverage for disaster prone area residents.127x Howard Kunreuther, The Role of Insurance in Reducing Losses from Extreme Events: The Need for Public-Private Partnerships, 40, Geneva Pap. Risk Insur., 741-762, 2015. Private insurers do not assume risks, but only administer policy coverage as the agent for FEMA. Moreover, there is no reinsurance arrangement in the NFIP. If claims exceed its financial capacity, the federal government provides bailout. This approach provides little advantage over a pure government-provided compensation programme, since the private insurers have no incentives to regulate policyholders’ behaviours and enhance the effectiveness of the programme.128x See Molk, supra note 126, at 424-425.
      The third model seems to stand in the middle of the above two approaches, where private insurers underwrite the disaster risk like many other lines in the private market, whilst the government acts as the last resort to provide additional capacity through reinsurance or other kinds of financial guarantee. The French Caisse Centrale de Réassurance (CCR), the U.S. federal-backed terrorism insurance and Turkish Catastrophe Insurance Pool are models of this approach. Take the French CCR as an example: the insurers are responsible for underwriting primary coverage, whilst the government provides subsidized reinsurance with an unlimited guarantee and cooperates with private insurers to create prevention and mitigation plans.129x Act No. 82-600 of 13 July 1982 on the Indemnification of Victims of Natural Catastrophes, JORF 14 July 1982, 2242. This enables primary insurers to underwrite disaster insurance policies at affordable prices for homeowners.130x Erwann Michel-Kerjan, Catastrophe Economics: The National Flood Insurance Program, 24, J. Econ. Perspect., 165-186, 2010. This model is more promising than the previous two, but is not perfect either. First, government-sponsored reinsurance generally offers subsidized premiums, which partially reduces incentives for disaster risk reduction.131x See Molk, supra note 126, at 424-425. Moreover, unlike private insurers, who face competitive pressure, governments face political pressure and, therefore, often apply a weaker pricing model. Again, the pricing may not sufficiently reflect risk and, therefore, not provide sufficient incentives for disaster risk reduction.132x Ibid., at 418-420. This model also requires a mandatory intervention by the government. Otherwise, private insurers would not be willing to cover correlated catastrophic losses.133x Ibid. See further on the role of the government as reinsurer of catastrophic risks, Bruggeman et al., supra note 101, at 369-390.

      II Outlook and Policy Recommendations for PPP

      The starting point for any recommendation is that an ex post compensation mechanism should always be structured in such a manner that it provides ex ante incentives for disaster risk reduction. The system requires ‘the potential to transfer risk to the party most able to bear it –that is, the party that can best manage it or mitigate it’.134x See Boardman et al., Greve & Hodge, supra note 121, at 444. These starting points have two important consequences for the role of the government in compensating victims of disaster.

      1. Stick to During Government Relief

      Most criticism on government-provided compensation efforts that we have examined above refer to ex post government recovery, rather than to during government relief. Undoubtedly, no one should object to the government providing emergency relief, including medical treatment, food, shelter and direct payment to victims during and in the aftermath of a disaster.135x See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 202. In addition, during government relief contributes to deal with the affordability issue of low-income residents for financial compensation solutions. It could “assist those who cannot afford to invest protective measures,…, against catastrophic losses for risks that are considered uninsurable by the private sector alone.”136x See Kunreuther, supra note 127, at 751.

      2. Facilitate the Ex ante Insurance

      In order to promote the role of ex ante insurance in compensating victims, the government should facilitate to solve the supply-and-demand barriers. To solve the supply barriers, the government could act as reinsurer to help fill the ‘capacity gap’ of primary insurers in underwriting disasters. Government-sponsored reinsurance can support failing insurance due to ‘a deep credit capacity’ of the government since it could raise money effectively and quickly through tax or issuing debt or bonds after disasters.137x See Kaplow, supra note 45, at 167-175. To solve the demand barriers, the government should reduce and even eliminate ex post government recovery and help solve the problem of adverse selection of potential victims with the provision of mandatory rules (like France’s mandatory comprehensive disaster insurance model138x Act No. 82-600 of 13 July 1982 on the Indemnification of Victims of Natural Catastrophes provides that “property insurance policies that cover damage against property are automatically and mandatorily insured against the risk of natural disasters”. Although natural catastrophe disasters are ‘non-insurable direct material damage,’ they must be insured in the Cat.Nat System (Art. L. 125-1 Insurance Code).). Furthermore, the government should provide public goods, like levees, and set rules and codes for disaster prevention to facilitate the insurance operation. Last but not the least, the government should pay special treatment to low-income residents. For example, it may provide means-tested vouchers which could cover part of the cost of insurance, and mitigation grants and loans, to those poor residents to afford insurance whilst keeping insurance premiums reflecting risk.139x Howard Kunreuther & Rosemary Lyster, The Role of Public and Private Insurance in Reducing Losses from Extreme Weather Events and Disasters,19, Asia Pac. J. Envtl. L., 29, 42-43, 2016.

    • F Conclusion

      Having started with a basic review of the evolution of disaster understanding and fundamental principles of victim compensation, we outlined and compared the government relief and recovery, insurance, PPPs in the framework of ex ante, during, and ex post timeline, to explore what kind of compensation mechanism could provide optimal incentives for disaster risk mitigation. By evaluating those mechanisms, we can observe serious limits in government-provided ex post recovery, and challenges in exclusive ex ante insurance. However, there is a remarkably dynamic partnership whereby compensation mechanisms interact in different stages of disaster management. Several recommendations are proposed on how a comprehensive PPP could be established.
      There are examples of legal systems that have already introduced the models we propose. In the EU, although compensation for disaster victims is often used as a political tool, European member states increasingly adopt a PPP mechanism whereby private insurance coverage is backed up with government-sponsored reinsurance. In China, the state still sticks to the praised during government relief, and, it gradually reduces the ex post government recovery by introducing ex ante insurance. Moreover, in the United States, especially after Hurricane Katrina, more suggestions are proposed to implement a PPP reform of the NIFP where primary insurers are responsible for underwriting flood risks and some type of federal reinsurance should be provided.140x See Kunreuther, supra note 127, at 741-762. Our analysis and recommendations may contribute to further research on this crucial topic and to a more effective compensation for disaster victims which equally contributes to disaster risk reduction.

    Noten

    • 1 Archive: Media Reports on Natural Disasters, available at: http://minervaextremelaw.haifa.ac.il/index.php/en/media-reports/24-media-reports/natural-disasters/237-archive-media-reports-on-natural-disasters-2017.

    • 2 Ibid.

    • 3 Muthukumara Mani, Michael Keen & Paul K. Freeman, Dealing with Increased Risk of Natural Disasters: Challenges and Options, IMF Working Paper, 2003, available at: www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2003/wp03197.pdf.

    • 4 Saul Levmore & Kyle D. Logue, Insuring Against Terrorism and Crime, 102, Mich. L. Rev., 268, 2003; Ronald J. Daniels, Donald F. Kettl & Howard Kunreuther, On Risk and Disaster: Lessons from Hurricane Katrina, 2006; William M. Taylor, Michael P. Levine, Oenone Rooksby & Joely-Kym Sobott, The ‘Katrina Effect’: On the Nature of Catastrophe, 2015.

    • 5 Reinhard Mechler & Jürgen Weichselgartner, Disaster Loss Financing in Germany – The Case of the Elbe River Floods 2002, IIASA Interim Report, IR-03-021, 2003.

    • 6 Qihao He, Climate Change, Catastrophe Risk, and Government Stimulation of the Insurance Market: A Study of Transitional China, in J. Jay Choi, Michael R. Powers & Xiaotian Tina Zhang (Eds.), The Political Economy of Chinese Finance, 295-340, 2016.

    • 7 Daniel Farber & Michael Faure, Introduction, in Daniel Farber & Michael Faure (Eds.), Disaster Law, Vol. xiii, 2010.

    • 8 For example, OECD, Catastrophic Risks and Insurance, 2005; Transboundary Risk Management, in Joanne Linnerooth-Bayer, Ragnar E. Lofstedt & Gunnar Sjostedt (Eds.), 2001; Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci & Michael G. Faure, The Economics of Disaster Relief, 37, Law & Pol’y., 180, 2015.

    • 9 Kristian Cedervall Lauta, Disaster Law, Vol. 8, 2015.

    • 10 Michael Faure, Towards Effective Compensation for Victims of Natural Catastrophes in Developing Countries, in Michael Faure & Andri Wibisana (Eds.), Regulating Disasters, Climate Change and Environmental Harm: Lessons from the Indonesian Experience, 244 , 2013.

    • 11 Omri Ben-Shahar & Kyle D. Logue, Outsourcing Regulation: How Insurance Reduces Moral Hazard, 111, Mich. L. Rev., 197, 233, 2011.

    • 12 Goetz von Peter et al., Unmitigated Disasters? New Evidence on the Macroeconomic Cost of Natural Catastrophes, 394, BIS Working Papers, 4, 16, 2012.

    • 13 See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 181.

    • 14 Just as Logue points, “[A]ccording to modern law-and-economics (‘L&E’) orthodoxy, the primary—maybe even the only—legitimate justification for government regulation is to correct a market failure.” See Kyle D. Logue, In Praise of (Some) Ex Post Regulation: A Response to Professor Galle, 69, Vand. L. Rev., en Banc 97, 2016.

    • 15 Herman B. Leonard & Arnold M. Howitt, Acting in Time against Disasters: A Comprehensive Risk-Management Framework, in Howard Kunreuther & Michael Useem (Eds.), Learning from Catastrophes: Strategies for Reaction and Response, 18-41, 2010.

    • 16 See Logue, supra note 14, at 122.

    • 17 Michael G. Faure, In the Aftermath of the Disaster: Liability and Compensation Mechanisms as Tools to Reduce Disaster Risks, 52, Stan. J. Int’l L., 95, 114-115, 2016.

    • 18 Ben Depoorter, Horizontal Political Externalities: The Supply and Demand of Disaster Management, 56, Duke L.J., 101, 2006.

    • 19 Ibid., at 104.

    • 20 George Priest, The Government, the Market and the Problem of Catastrophic Loss, 12, J. Risk Uncertain., 221, 1996; Howard Kunreuther, Mitigating Disaster Losses through Insurance, 12, J. Risk Uncertain., 171, 1996.

    • 21 See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 180.

    • 22 Robert B. Ahdieh, Reanalyzing Cost-Benefit Analysis: Toward a Framework of Function(s) and Form(s), 88, N.Y.U. L. Rev., 1983, 2013.

    • 23 Whereas prevention is aimed at reducing the probability that damage will occur in the event of a disaster, mitigation aims at reducing the extent of the damage once the disaster has occurred.

    • 24 See Faure, supra note 17, at 99.

    • 25 Lauta, supra note 9.

    • 26 Ibid., at 36.

    • 27 Thomas Kuhn, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, 1970.

    • 28 Lauta, supra note 9, at 14-22; Frank Furedi, The Changing Meaning of Disaster, 39, Area, 482, 2007.

    • 29 Ben Wisner, Ilan Kelman & J.C. Gaillard, Hazard, Vulnerability, Capacity, Risk and Participation, in Alejandro et al. (Eds.), Disaster Management, International Lessons in Risk Reduction, Response, and Recovery, 14, 2014.

    • 30 See Depoorter, supra note 18, at 101-125; Kip W. Viscusi, The Hold-Up Problem. Why It Is Urgent to Rethink the Economics of Disaster Insurance Protection, in Erwann Michel-Kerjan & Paul Slovic (Eds.), The Irrational Economist. Making Decisions in a Dangerous World, 142-148, 2010.

    • 31 Michael Faure, Liability and Compensation for Damage Resulting from CO2 Storage Sites, 40, Wm. & Mary Envtl. L. & Pol’y Rev., 387, 437, 2016.

    • 32 Michael Faure, A Multilayered Approach to Cover Damages Caused by Offshore Facilities, 33, Va. Envtl. L.J. 357, 403, 2015.

    • 33 Howard Kunreuther, The Case for Comprehensive Disaster Insurance, 11, J. L. & Econ., 133-163, 1968; Richard A. Epstein, Catastrophe Responses to Catastrophe Risks, 12, J. Risk Uncertain., 287-308, 1996.

    • 34 Michael Faure, Climate Change Adaption and Compensation, in Jonathan Verschuuren (Ed.), Research Handbook on Climate Change Adaptation Law, 114-115, 2013.

    • 35 See Steven Garber, Designing Compensation Programs for Individuals and Households after Man-Made and Natural Disasters in the United States, 45-46, 2016.

    • 36 See Faure, supra note 34, at 115.

    • 37 See, e.g. Carolyn Kousky & Howard Kunreuther, Addressing Affordability in the National Flood Insurance Program, Resources for the Future and Wharton Risk Management and Decision Process Center, August 2013.

    • 38 See Priest, supra note 20, at 235.

    • 39 Ibid.

    • 40 Reimund Schwarze & Gert Wagner, In the Aftermath of Dresden: New Directions in German Flood Insurance, 29, Geneva Pap. Risk Insur., 154, 154-168, 2004.

    • 41 David M. Cutler & Richard J. Zeckhauser, Reinsurance for Catastrophes and Cataclysms, in Kenneth A. Froot (Ed.), The Financing of Catastrophe Risk, 258-259, 1999; Howard Kunreuther & Erwann Michel-Kerjan, Challenges for Terrorism Risk Insurance in the United States, 18, J. Econ. Persp., 201, 2004.

    • 42 Levmore & Logue, supra note 4, at 310.

    • 43 Lisa Grow Sun, Disaster Mythology and the Law, 96, Cornell L. Rev., 1131, 2011.

    • 44 Thomas A. Garrett, Thomas L. Marsh & Maria I. Marshall, Political Allocation of US Agriculture Disaster Payments in the 1990s, 26, Int. Rev. Law Econ., 143-161, 2006.

    • 45 Louis Kaplow, Incentives and Government Relief for Risk, 4, J. Risk Uncertain., 167-175, 1991.

    • 46 Richard Epstein even calls this form of compensation: “Catastrophic responses to catastrophic risk” (Epstein, supra note 33.

    • 47 See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 183-184.

    • 48 For example, Edward M. Iacobucci, Michael J. Trebilcock & Huma Haider, Economic Shocks: Defining a Role for Government, 2001; Brian Galle, in Praise of Ex Ante Regulation, 68 Vand. L. Rev., 1715, 2015; see Logue, supra note 14, at 122.

    • 49 See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 185. Take the United States, e.g. federal relief efforts include “coordinating necessary decisions, support[ing] search and rescue efforts, and […] provid[ing] public health, medical and mental health support at casualty evacuation points and refugee shelters”. See Report: Disaster Evacuation. Cong Bea, Research Serve; Disaster Evacuation and Displacement Policy: Issues for Congress 2005, 2-3, available at: www.everycrsreport.com/files/20060817_RS22235_cc0ebce1cf39f6a7c5f7d52b106084bc40ca427e.pdf.

    • 50 Homeland Security Today, Funding the first 72 hours, available at: https://www.hstoday.us/channels/fema/funding-the-first-72-hours/.

    • 51 Jacob Hunter, Why the First 72 Hours After a Disaster Are Critical, available at: www.primalsurvivor.net/why-the-first-72-hours-after-a-disaster-are-critical/.

    • 52 Michael Trebilcock & Ronald J. Daniels, Rationales and Instruments for Government Intervention, in Ronald J. Daniels, Donald F. Kettl & Howard Kunreuther (Eds.), On Risk and Disaster: Lessons from Hurricane Katrina, 89-107, 2006.

    • 53 See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 186.

    • 54 Ibid., at 199.

    • 55 William F. Shughart, Katrinanomics: The Politics and Economics of Disaster Relief, 127, Public Choice, 31-53, 2006.

    • 56 Ibid.

    • 57 Hu Jintao, Address on the National Earthquake Relief Summary Commendation Conference [Zai Quanguo Kangzhen Jiuzai Zongjie Biaozhang Dahui Shangde Jianghua], 2008.

    • 58 Xinhua News Agency, Central Government Appropriated $ 400 Million to Earthquake Relief, 15 May 2008, available at: http://news.xinhuanet.com/newscenter/2008-05/15/content_8180172.htm.

    • 59 Peijun Shi & Xin Zhang, Chinese Mechanism against Catastrophe Risk – The Experience of Great Sichuan Earthquake, 28, J. Tsinghua Univ. (Philosophy and Social Sciences), 96-113, 2013.

    • 60 Office of the National Commission for Disaster Reduction, P.R. China, China’s Natural Disaster Risk Management, in Improving the Assessment of Disaster Risks to Strengthen Financial Resilience, 121-131, A Special Joint G20 Publication by the Government of Mexico and the World Bank, 2012.

    • 61 Jiang Lingling et al., People’s Republic of China: Providing Emergency Response to Sichuan Earthquake, Technical Assistance Consultant’s Report to Ministry of Civil Affairs, P.R. China and Asian Development Bank, 2008.

    • 62 Ibid.

    • 63 Kristin Dalen, Hedda Flatø, Liu Jing & Zhang Huafeng, Recovering from the Wenchuan Earthquake. Living Conditions and Development in Disaster Areas 2008-2011, Fafo-Report 2012, 39, 2012.

    • 64 Ibid.

    • 65 Barry Naughton, China’s Economy: Complacency, Crisis & the Challenge of Reform, 143, Daedalus, 14-25, 2014.

    • 66 Yi-Ming Wei, Ju-Liang Jin & Qiong Wang, Impacts of Natural Disasters and Disaster Risk Management in China: The Case of China’s Experience in Wenchuan Earthquake, in Yasuyuki Sawada & Sothea Oum (Eds.), Economic and Welfare Impacts of Disasters in East Asia and Policy Responses, 641-675, 2012.

    • 67 Jian Zhang, The Military and Disaster Relief in China: Trends, Drivers and Implications, in Minako Sakai et al. (Eds.), Disaster Relief in the Asia Pacific: Agency and Resilience, 79-80, 2014.

    • 68 Dalen et al., supra note 63.

    • 69 In the sense that ex post recovery does negatively affect the incentives to invest in disaster risk reduction. The same is not the case with during relief. See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8.

    • 70 Tola Amodu, Michael Faure & Ton Hartlief (Eds.), Financial Compensation for Victims of Catastrophes: A Comparative Legal Approach, 2006.

    • 71 Michael Faure, Financial Compensation for Victims of Catastrophes: A Law and Economics Perspective, 29, L. & Pol’y., 339, 353, 2007.

    • 72 Alberto Monti & Filippo Andrea Chiaves, Italy, in Michael Faure & Ton Hartlief (Eds.), Financial Compensation for Victims of Catastrophes: A Comparative Legal Approach, 145-194, 2006.

    • 73 Justin Pidot, Deconstructing Disaster, 2013, BYU L. Rev., 213, 2013.

    • 74 See Depoorter, supra note 18, at 101.

    • 75 Oliver Houck, Can We Save New Orleans? 19, Tul. Envtl. L. J., 1, 2006; William L. Waugh Jr., The Disaster That Was Katrina, Natural Hazards Observer, 30, 2005

    • 76 Paul A. Raschky & Hannelore Weck-Hannemann, Charity Hazard – A Real Hazard to Natural Disaster Insurance? 7, Envtl. Hazards, 321, 2007.

    • 77 See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 182.

    • 78 Theodore Talbot & Owen Barder, Payouts for Perils: Why Disaster Aid Is Broken, and How Catastrophe Insurance Can Help to Fix It, CGD Policy Paper 087, Washington, D.C: Center for Global Development, 2016, available at:. www.cgdev.org/sites/default/files/payouts-perils-why-disaster-aid-broken-and-how-catastrophe-insurance-can-help-fix-it-0.pdf.

    • 79 Christopher B. Barrett, Does Food Aid Stabilize Food Availability?, 49, Econ. Dev. Cult. Change, 335-349, 2001; Polly J. Diven, The Domestic Determinants of US Food Aid Policy, 26, Food Policy, 455-474, 2001.

    • 80 See Sun, supra note, at 45.

    • 81 Erwann Michel-Kerjan, Haven’t You Switched to Risk Management 2.0 Yet?, in Erwann Michel-Kerjan & Paul Slovic (Eds.), The Irrational Economist: Making Decisions in a Dangerous World, 41-46, 2010.

    • 82 See Depoorter, supra note 18, at 101.

    • 83 Richard Zeckhauser, The Economics of Catastrophes, 12, J. Risk Uncertain., 134, 1996.

    • 84 Levmore & Logue, supra note 4, at 281.

    • 85 Christian Gollier (Ed.), Some Aspects of the Economics of Catastrophe Risk Insurance, in Catastrophic Risks and Insurance, 13-30, 2005.

    • 86 Marcel A.P.M. van Asseldonk, Miranda P.M. Meuwissen & Ruud B.M. Huirne, Belief in Disaster Relief and the Demand for a Public-Private Insurance Program, 24, Rev. Agric. Econ., 196, 2002.

    • 87 Veronique Bruggeman, Michael G. Faure & Miriam Haritz, Remodeling Reparation: Changes in the Compensation of Victims of Natural Catastrophes in Belgium and the Netherlands, 35, Disasters, 766, 767, 780, 2011.

    • 88 See Faure, supra note 10, at 442-444.

    • 89 There is, however, an EU Solidarity Fund to deal with major natural disasters, as that provides help to member states rather than directly to victims. See Regulation 661/2014 amending Council Regulation 2012/2002 establishing the European Solidarity Fund, OJ L 189 of 27 June 2014.

    • 90 Michel Cannarsa, Fabien Lafay & Olivier Moréteau, France, in Michael Faure & Ton Hartlief (Eds.), Financial Compensation for Victims of Catastrophes: A Comparative Legal Approach, 81-118, 2006; Howard Kunreuther, Has the Time Come for Comprehensive Natural Disaster Insurance? in Ronald J. Daniels, Donald F. Kettle & Howard Kunreuther (Eds.), On Risk and Disaster: Lessons from Hurricane Katrina, 175-201, 2006.

    • 91 Bruggeman et al., supra note 87, at 767.

    • 92 Robert Cooter & Thomas Ulen, Law & Economics, 4, 5th ed., 2008.

    • 93 Howard Kunreuther, Erwann Michel-Kerjan & Nicola Ranger, Insuring Future Climate Catastrophes, 118, Climate Change, 339, 2013; see Kunreuther, supra note 33, at 133.

    • 94 See Faure, supra note 17, at 101; see Priest, supra note 20, at 221-225 (arguing that private insurance is able, via the control of the moral hazard by insurers, to provide incentives for mitigation of disaster risks).

    • 95 Faure, supra note 17, at 101-102.

    • 96 See Epstein, supra note 33, at 297; see Kaplow, supra note 45, at 167 (holding that ex post government compensation can negatively affect incentives for prevention).

    • 97 Anne Gron & Alan O. Sykes, Terrorism and Insurance Markets: A Role for the Government as Insurer?, 36, Indiana L. Rev., 447, 447-463, 2003.

    • 98 See Epstein, supra note 33, at 287.

    • 99 See Garber, supra note 35, at 46.

    • 100 Dwight Jaffe & Thomas Russell, Catastrophe Insurance, Capital Markets, and Uninsured Risks, 62, J. Risk Insur., 225-230, 1997; Howard Kunreuther, Mitigating Disaster Losses through Insurance, 12, J. Risk Uncertain., 171-187, 1996; Veronique Bruggeman, Michael Faure & Karine Fiore, The Government as Reinsurer of Catastrophe Risks?, 35, Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. Issues Pract., 369-390, 2010.

    • 101 Although there have been some exceptional cases of disaster cover via the government at lower costs than the market. See on this case of so-called efficient monopolies Thomas von Ungern-Sternberg, The Limits of Competition: Housing Insurance in Switzerland, 40, Eur. Econ. Rev., 1113-1114, 1996; Véronique Bruggeman, Michael Faure & Tobias Heldt, Insurance against Catastrophe: Government Stimulation of Insurance Markets for Catastrophic Events, 23, Duke Envtl. L. Pol’y Forum, 212-218, 2012.

    • 102 Kenneth S. Abraham, Insurance Law and Regulation, 7, 5th ed., 2010.

    • 103 For example, Bengt Hölmstrom, Moral Hazard and Observability, 10, Bell J. Econ.,74, 1979; Tom Baker, On the Genealogy of Moral Hazard, 75, Tex. L. Rev., 237, 1996.

    • 104 Carol Heimer, Insuring More, Ensuring Less: The Costs and Benefits of Private Regulation through Insurance, in Tom Baker & Jonathan Simon (Eds.), Embracing Risk: The Changing Culture of Insurance and Responsibility, 117-145, 2002.

    • 105 See Shahar & Logue, supra note 11, at 111; Tom Baker & Rick Swedloff, Regulation by Liability Insurance: From Auto to Lawyers Professional Liability, 60, UCLA L. Rev., 1412, 2013; ShauhinTalesh, Legal Intermediaries: How Insurance Companies Construct the Meaning of Compliance with Anti-Discrimination Laws, 37, L. & Pol’y., 209, 2015.

    • 106 Howard Kunreuther, Reducing Losses from Catastrophe Risks through Long-Term Insurance and Mitigation, 75, Social Res., 905, 916, 2008.

    • 107 See Baker & Swedloff, supra note 105, at 1420-1421.

    • 108 Swenja Surminski, The Role of Insurance in Reducing Direct Risk: the Case of Flood Insurance, 7, Int. Rev. Envtl. Res. Econ., 241, 264, 2013.

    • 109 Sean B. Hecht, Climate Change and the Transformation of Risk: Insurance Matters, 55, UCLA L. Rev., 1559, 1586, 2008.

    • 110 For example, in the United States, the biggest private insurance market in the world, after Hurricane Katrina in 2005, numerous insurance firms cut back their coverage in coastal areas. As of 2012, many catastrophe losses remained uninsured. See Swiss Re, Natural Catastrophes and Man-made Disasters in 2012: A Year of Extreme Weather Events in the US, 2013, available at:. https://www.swissre.com/institute/research/sigma-research/sigma-2013-02.html.

    • 111 Qihao He, Mitigation of Climate Change Risks and Regulation by Insurance: A Feasible Proposal for China, 43, B.C. Envtl. Aff. L. Rev., 319, 339, 2016.

    • 112 Daniel Kahneman, Thinking, Fast and Slow, 20-21, 2011.

    • 113 Shlomo Benartzi & Richard Thaleer, Myopic Loss Aversion and the Equity Premium Puzzle, 110, Q. J. Econ., 73-92, 1995.

    • 114 Paul Slovic, Howard Kunreuther & Gilbert F. White, Decision Processes, Rationality and Adjustment to Natural Hazards, in Paul Slovic (Ed.), The Perception of Risk, 1-31, 2000.

    • 115 Farber & Faure, supra note 7, at xix.

    • 116 Howard Kunreuther, Mark V. Pauly & Stacey McMorrow, Insurance and Behavioral Economics: Improving Decisions in the Most Misunderstood Industry, 114-115, 2013.

    • 117 Stephen Coate, Altruism, the Samaritan’s Dilemma, and Government Transfer Policy, 85, Am. Econ. Rev., 46-57, 1995.

    • 118 Steven Shavell, A General Rationale for a Governmental Role in the Relief of Large Risks, 49, J., Risk Uncertain., 213, 214, 2014.

    • 119 Ibid., at 215.

    • 120 See Kunreuther et al., supra note 116, at 113-118.

    • 121 Anthony E. Boardman, Carsten Greve & Graeme A. Hodge, Comparative Analyses of Infrastructure Public-Private Partnerships, 17, J. Comp. Policy Anal. Res. Pract., 441, 442, 2015.

    • 122 A.J. Smith, Privatized Infrastructure: The Role of Government, 1999.

    • 123 Michael Huber, Insurability and Regulatory Reform: Is the English Flood Insurance Regime Able to Adapt to Climate Change?, 29, Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. Issues Pract., 169-182, 2004.

    • 124 The Flood Re model is loosely based on Pool Re, a reinsurance scheme for terrorism risks formed in 1993 in response to the threat posed by the Irish Republican Army and other terrorist activity. See Johanna Hjalmarsson & Mateusz Bek, Legislative and Regulatory Methodology and Approach: Developing Catastrophe Insurance in China, in Johanna Hjalmarsson & Dingjing Huang (Eds.), Insurance Law in China, 197, 2015.

    • 125 Flood Re, Incentivising Household Action on Flooding and Options for Using Incentives to Increase the Take- Up of Flood Resilience and Resistance Measures, 2018, available at: www.floodre.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/Flood-Re_Position-on-Incentives_SMF-report.pdf.

    • 126 Peter Molk, The Government’s Role in Climate Change Insurance, 43, B.C. Envtl. Aff. L. Rev., 411, 424, 2016.

    • 127 Howard Kunreuther, The Role of Insurance in Reducing Losses from Extreme Events: The Need for Public-Private Partnerships, 40, Geneva Pap. Risk Insur., 741-762, 2015.

    • 128 See Molk, supra note 126, at 424-425.

    • 129 Act No. 82-600 of 13 July 1982 on the Indemnification of Victims of Natural Catastrophes, JORF 14 July 1982, 2242.

    • 130 Erwann Michel-Kerjan, Catastrophe Economics: The National Flood Insurance Program, 24, J. Econ. Perspect., 165-186, 2010.

    • 131 See Molk, supra note 126, at 424-425.

    • 132 Ibid., at 418-420.

    • 133 Ibid. See further on the role of the government as reinsurer of catastrophic risks, Bruggeman et al., supra note 101, at 369-390.

    • 134 See Boardman et al., Greve & Hodge, supra note 121, at 444.

    • 135 See Dari-Mattiacci & Faure, supra note 8, at 202.

    • 136 See Kunreuther, supra note 127, at 751.

    • 137 See Kaplow, supra note 45, at 167-175.

    • 138 Act No. 82-600 of 13 July 1982 on the Indemnification of Victims of Natural Catastrophes provides that “property insurance policies that cover damage against property are automatically and mandatorily insured against the risk of natural disasters”. Although natural catastrophe disasters are ‘non-insurable direct material damage,’ they must be insured in the Cat.Nat System (Art. L. 125-1 Insurance Code).

    • 139 Howard Kunreuther & Rosemary Lyster, The Role of Public and Private Insurance in Reducing Losses from Extreme Weather Events and Disasters,19, Asia Pac. J. Envtl. L., 29, 42-43, 2016.

    • 140 See Kunreuther, supra note 127, at 741-762.


Print this article